Federal Reserve System

The entity responsible for overseeing the monetary system for a nation (or group of nations). Central banks have a wide range of responsibilities, from overseeing monetary policy to implementing specific goals such as currency stability, low inflation and full employment. Central banks also generally issue currency, function as the bank of the government, regulate the credit system, oversee commercial banks, manage exchange reserves and act as a lender of last resort.

The central banking system in the U. S. is known as the Federal Reserve System (commonly known as "the Fed"), which is composed of 12 regional Federal Reserve Banks located in major cities throughout the country. The main tasks of the Federal Reserve are to supervise and regulate banks, implement monetary policy by buying and selling U. S. Treasury bonds and steer interest rates. Ben Bernanke currently serves as the chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. central bank

A nation's principal monetary authority, such as the Federal Reserve Bank, which regulates the money supply and credit, issues currency, and manages the rate of exchange. central bank - a government monetary authority that issues currency and regulates the supply of credit and holds the reserves of other banks and sells new issues of securities for the government central bank- a national bank that does business mainly with a government and with other banks: it regulates the volume and cost of credit B.

Overview of Functions and Operations Objectives The BSP’s primary objective is to maintain price stability conducive to a balanced and sustainable economic growth. The BSP also aims to promote and preserve monetary stability and the convertibility of the national currency. Responsibilities The BSP provides policy directions in the areas of money, banking and credit. It supervises operations of banks and exercises regulatory powers over non-bank financial institutions with quasi-banking functions.

Under the New Central Bank Act, the BSP performs the following functions, all of which relate to its status as the Republic’s central monetary authority. Liquidity Management. The BSP formulates and implements monetary policy aimed at influencing money supply consistent with its primary objective to maintain price stability. Currency issue. The BSP has the exclusive power to issue the national currency. All notes and coins issued by the BSP are fully guaranteed by the Government and are considered legal tender for all private and public debts.

Lender of last resort. The BSP extends discounts, loans and advances to banking institutions for liquidity purposes. Financial Supervision. The BSP supervises banks and exercises regulatory powers over non-bank institutions performing quasi-banking functions. Management of foreign currency reserves. The BSP seeks to maintain sufficient international reserves to meet any foreseeable net demands for foreign currencies in order to preserve the international stability and convertibility of the Philippine peso. Determination of exchange rate policy.

The BSP determines the exchange rate policy of the Philippines. Currently, the BSP adheres to a market-oriented foreign exchange rate policy such that the role of Bangko Sentral is principally to ensure orderly conditions in the market. Other activities. The BSP functions as the banker, financial advisor and official depository of the Government, its political subdivisions and instrumentalities and government-owned and -controlled corporations. The central bank generally performs the following functions: 1. Bank of Note Issue:

The central bank has the sole monopoly of note issue in almost every country. The currency notes printed and issued by the central bank become unlimited legal tender throughout the country. In the words of De Kock, "The privilege of note-issue was almost everywhere associated with the origin and development of central banks. " However, the monopoly of central bank to issue the currency notes may be partial in certain countries. For example, in India, one rupee notes are issued by the Ministry of Finance and all other notes are issued by the Reserve Bank of India.

The main advantages of giving the monopoly right of note issue to the central bank are given below: (i) It brings uniformity in the monetary system of note issue and note circulation. (ii) The central bank can exercise better control over the money supply in the country. It increases public confidence in the monetary system of the country. (iii) Monetary management of the paper currency becomes easier. Being the supreme bank of the country, the central bank has full information about the monetary requirements of the economy and, therefore, can change the quantity of currency accordingly.

(iv) It enables the central bank to exercise control over the creation of credit by the commercial banks. (v) The central bank also earns profit from the issue of paper currency. (vi) Granting of monopoly right of note issue to the central bank avoids the political interference in the matter of note issue. 2. Banker, Agent and Adviser to the Government: The central bank functions as a banker, agent and financial adviser to the government, (a) As a banker to government, the central bank performs the same functions for the government as a commercial bank performs for its customers.

It maintains the accounts of the central as well as state government; it receives deposits from government; it makes short-term advances to the government; it collects cheques and drafts deposited in the government account; it provides foreign exchange resources to the government for repaying external debt or purchasing foreign goods or making other payments, (b) As an Agent to the government, the central bank collects taxes and other payments on behalf of the government. It raises loans from the public and thus manages public debt.

It also represents the government in the international financial institutions and conferences, (c) As a financial adviser to the lent, the central bank gives advise to the government on economic, monetary, financial and fiscal ^natters such as deficit financing, devaluation, trade policy, foreign exchange policy, etc. 3. Bankers' Bank: The central bank acts as the bankers' bank in three capacities: (a) Custodian of the cash preserves of the commercial banks; (b) As the lender of the last resort; and (c) as clearing agent.

In this way, the central bank acts as a friend, philosopher and guide to the commercial banks As a custodian of the cash reserves of the commercial banks the central bank maintains the cash reserves of the commercial banks. Every commercial bank has to keep a certain percentage of its cash balances as deposits with the central banks. These cash reserves can be utilized by the commercial banks in times of emergency. The centralization of cash reserves in the central bank has the following advantages: (i) Centralized cash reserves inspire confidence of the public in the banking system of the country.

(ii) Centralized cash reserves provide the basis of a larger and more elastic credit structure than if these amounts were scattered among the individual banks. (iii) Centralized reserves can be used to the fullest possible extent and in the most effective manner during the periods of seasonal strains and financial emergencies. (iv) Centralized reserves enable the central bank to provide financial accommodation to the commercial banks which are in temporary difficulties.

In fact the central bank functions as the lender of the last resort on the basis of the centralized cash reserves. (v) The system of centralized cash reserves enables the central bank to influence the creation of credit by the commercial banks by increasing or decreasing the cash reserves through the technique of variable cash-reserve ratio. (vi) The cash reserves with the central bank can be used to promote national welfare. 4. Lender of Last Resort: As the supreme bank of the country and the bankers' bank, the central bank acts as the lender of the last resort.

In other words, in case the commercial banks are not able to meet their financial requirements from other sources, they can, as a last resort, approach the central bank for financial accommodation. The central bank provides financial accommodation to the commercial banks by rediscounting their eligible securities and exchange bills. The main advantages of the central bank's functioning as the lender of the last resort are : (i) It increases the elasticity and liquidity of the whole credit structure of the economy. (ii) It enables the commercial banks to carry on their activities even with their limited cash reserves.

(iii) It provides financial help to the commercial banks in times of emergency. (iv) It enables the central bank to exercise its control over banking system of the country. 5. Clearing Agent: As the custodian of the cash reserves of the commercial banks, the central bank acts as the clearing house for these banks. Since all banks have their accounts with the central bank, the central bank can easily settle the claims of various banks against each other with least use of cash. The clearing house function of the central bank has the following advantages: (i) It economies the use of cash by banks while settling their claims and counter-claims.

(i) It reduces the withdrawals of cash and these enable the commercial banks to create credit on a large scale. (ii) It keeps the central bank fully informed about the liquidity position of the commercial banks. http://www. preservearticles. com/201012281868/functions-of-central-bank. html C. A Brief History of Central Banks Michael D. Bordo One of the world’s foremost economic historians explains the forces behind the development of modern central banks, providing insight into their role in the financial system and the economy.

A central bank is the term used to describe the authority responsible for policies that affect a country’s supply of money and credit. More specifically, a central bank uses its tools of monetary policy—open market operations, discount window lending, changes in reserve requirements—to affect short-term interest rates and the monetary base (currency held by the public plus bank reserves) and to achieve important policy goals. There are three key goals of modern monetary policy. The first and most important is price stability or stability in the value of money. Today this means maintaining a sustained low rate of inflation.

The second goal is a stable real economy, often interpreted as high employment and high and sustainable economic growth. Another way to put it is to say that monetary policy is expected to smooth the business cycle and offset shocks to the economy. The third goal is financial stability. This encompasses an efficient and smoothly running payments system and the prevention of financial crises. Beginnings The story of central banking goes back at least to the seventeenth century, to the founding of the first institution recognized as a central bank, the Swedish Riksbank.

Established in 1668 as a joint stock bank, it was chartered to lend the government funds and to act as a clearing house for commerce. A few decades later (1694), the most famous central bank of the era, the Bank of England, was founded also as a joint stock company to purchase government debt. Other central banks were set up later in Europe for similar purposes, though some were established to deal with monetary disarray. For example, the Banque de France was established by Napoleon in 1800 to stabilize the currency after the hyperinflation of paper money during the French Revolution, as well as to aid in government finance.

Early central banks issued private notes which served as currency, and they often had a monopoly over such note issue. While these early central banks helped fund the government’s debt, they were also private entities that engaged in banking activities. Because they held the deposits of other banks, they came to serve as banks for bankers, facilitating transactions between banks or providing other banking services. They became the repository for most banks in the banking system because of their large reserves and extensive networks of correspondent banks.

These factors allowed them to become the lender of last resort in the face of a financial crisis. In other words, they became willing to provide emergency cash to their correspondents in times of financial distress. Transition The Federal Reserve System belongs to a later wave of central banks, which emerged at the turn of the twentieth century. These banks were created primarily to consolidate the various instruments that people were using for currency and to provide financial stability. Many also were created to manage the gold standard, to which most countries adhered.

The gold standard, which prevailed until 1914, meant that each country defined its currency in terms of a fixed weight of gold. Central banks held large gold reserves to ensure that their notes could be converted into gold, as was required by their charters. When their reserves declined because of a balance of payments deficit or adverse domestic circumstances, they would raise their discount rates (the interest rates at which they would lend money to the other banks). Doing so would raise interest rates more generally, which in turn attracted foreign investment, thereby bringing more gold into the country.

Central banks adhered to the gold standard’s rule of maintaining gold convertibility above all other considerations. Gold convertibility served as the economy’s nominal anchor. That is, the amount of money banks could supply was constrained by the value of the gold they held in reserve, and this in turn determined the prevailing price level. And because the price level was tied to a known commodity whose long-run value was determined by market forces, expectations about the future price level were tied to it as well.

In a sense, early central banks were strongly committed to price stability. They did not worry too much about one of the modern goals of central banking—the stability of the real economy—because they were constrained by their obligation to adhere to the gold standard. Central banks of this era also learned to act as lenders of last resort in times of financial stress—when events like bad harvests, defaults by railroads, or wars precipitated a scramble for liquidity (in which depositors ran to their banks and tried to convert their deposits into cash).

The lesson began early in the nineteenth century as a consequence of the Bank of England’s routine response to such panics. At the time, the Bank (and other European central banks) would often protect their own gold reserves first, turning away their correspondents in need. Doing so precipitated major panics in 1825, 1837, 1847, and 1857, and led to severe criticism of the Bank. In response, the Bank adopted the “responsibility doctrine,” proposed by the economic writer Walter Bagehot, which required the Bank to subsume its private interest to the public interest of the banking system as a whole.

The Bank began to follow Bagehot’s rule, which was to lend freely on the basis of any sound collateral offered—but at a penalty rate (that is, above market rates) to prevent moral hazard. The bank learned its lesson well. No financial crises occurred in England for nearly 150 years after 1866. It wasn’t until August 2007 that the country experienced its next crisis. The U. S. experience was most interesting. It had two central banks in the early nineteenth century, the Bank of the United States (1791–1811) and a second Bank of the United States (1816–1836).

Both were set up on the model of the Bank of England, but unlike the British, Americans bore a deep-seated distrust of any concentration of financial power in general, and of central banks in particular, so that in each case, the charters were not renewed. There followed an 80-year period characterized by considerable financial instability. Between 1836 and the onset of the Civil War—a period known as the Free Banking Era—states allowed virtual free entry into banking with minimal regulation. Throughout the period, banks failed frequently, and several banking panics occurred.

The payments system was notoriously inefficient, with thousands of dissimilar-looking state bank notes and counterfeits in circulation. In response, the government created the national banking system during the Civil War. While the system improved the efficiency of the payments system by providing a uniform currency based on national bank notes, it still provided no lender of last resort, and the era was rife with severe banking panics. The crisis of 1907 was the straw that broke the camel’s back.

It led to the creation of the Federal Reserve in 1913, which was given the mandate of providing a uniform and elastic currency (that is, one which would accommodate the seasonal, cyclical, and secular movements in the economy) and to serve as a lender of last resort. The Genesis of Modern Central Banking Goals Before 1914, central banks didn’t attach great weight to the goal of maintaining the domestic economy’s stability. This changed after World War I, when they began to be concerned about employment, real activity, and the price level.

The shift reflected a change in the political economy of many countries—suffrage was expanding, labor movements were rising, and restrictions on migration were being set. In the 1920s, the Fed began focussing on both external stability (which meant keeping an eye on gold reserves, because the U. S. was still on the gold standard) and internal stability (which meant keeping an eye on prices, output, and employment). But as long as the gold standard prevailed, external goals dominated. Unfortunately, the Fed’s monetary policy led to serious problems in the 1920s and 1930s.

When it came to managing the nation’s quantity of money, the Fed followed a principle called the real bills doctrine. The doctrine argued that the quantity of money needed in the economy would naturally be supplied so long as Reserve Banks lent funds only when banks presented eligible self-liquidating commercial paper for collateral. One corollary of the real bills doctrine was that the Fed should not permit bank lending to finance stock market speculation, which explains why it followed a tight policy in 1928 to offset the Wall Street boom.

The policy led to the beginning of recession in August 1929 and the crash in October. Then, in the face of a series of banking panics between 1930 and 1933, the Fed failed to act as a lender of last resort. As a result, the money supply collapsed, and massive deflation and depression followed. The Fed erred because the real bills doctrine led it to interpret the prevailing low short-term nominal interest rates as a sign of monetary ease, and they believed no banks needed funds because very few member banks came to the discount window. After the Great Depression, the Federal Reserve System was reorganized.

The Banking Acts of 1933 and 1935 shifted power definitively from the Reserve Banks to the Board of Governors. In addition, the Fed was made subservient to the Treasury. The Fed regained its independence from the Treasury in 1951, whereupon it began following a deliberate countercyclical policy under the directorship of William McChesney Martin. During the 1950s this policy was quite successful in ameliorating several recessions and in maintaining low inflation. At the time, the United States and the other advanced countries were part of the Bretton Woods System, under which the U.S. pegged the dollar to gold at $35 per ounce and the other countries pegged to the dollar.

The link to gold may have carried over some of the credibility of a nominal anchor and helped to keep inflation low. The picture changed dramatically in the 1960s when the Fed began following a more activist stabilization policy. In this decade it shifted its priorities from low inflation toward high employment. Possible reasons include the adoption of Keynesian ideas and the belief in the Phillips curve trade-off between inflation and unemployment.

The consequence of the shift in policy was the buildup of inflationary pressures from the late 1960s until the end of the 1970s. The causes of the Great Inflation are still being debated, but the era is renowned as one of the low points in Fed history. The restraining influence of the nominal anchor disappeared, and for the next two decades, inflation expectations took off. The inflation ended with Paul Volcker’s shock therapy from 1979 to 1982, which involved monetary tightening and the raising of policy interest rates to double digits.

The Volcker shock led to a sharp recession, but it was successful in breaking the back of high inflation expectations. In the following decades, inflation declined significantly and has stayed low ever since. Since the early 1990s the Fed has followed a policy of implicit inflation targeting, using the federal funds rate as its policy instrument. In many respects, the policy regime currently followed echoes the convertibility principle of the gold standard, in the sense that the public has come to believe in the credibility of the Fed’s commitment to low inflation.

A key force in the history of central banking has been central bank independence. The original central banks were private and independent. They depended on the government to maintain their charters but were otherwise free to choose their own tools and policies. Their goals were constrained by gold convertibility. In the twentieth century, most of these central banks were nationalized and completely lost their independence. Their policies were dictated by the fiscal authorities. The Fed regained its independence after 1951, but its independence is not absolute.

It must report to Congress, which ultimately has the power to change the Federal Reserve Act. Other central banks had to wait until the 1990s to regain their independence. Financial Stability An increasingly important role for central banks is financial stability. The evolution of this responsibility has been similar across the advanced countries. In the gold standard era, central banks developed a lender-of-last-resort function, following Bagehot’s rule. But financial systems became unstable between the world wars, as widespread banking crises plagued the early 1920s and the 1930s.

The experience of the Fed was the worst. The response to banking crises in Europe at the time was generally to bail out the troubled banks with public funds. This approach was later adopted by the United States with the Reconstruction Finance Corporation, but on a limited scale. After the Depression, every country established a financial safety net, comprising deposit insurance and heavy regulation that included interest rate ceilings and firewalls between financial and commercial institutions.

As a result, there were no banking crises from the late 1930s until the mid-1970s anywhere in the advanced world. This changed dramatically in the 1970s. The Great Inflation undermined interest rate ceilings and inspired financial innovations designed to circumvent the ceilings and other restrictions. These innovations led to deregulation and increased competition. Banking instability reemerged in the United States and abroad, with such examples of large-scale financial disturbances as the failures of Franklin National in 1974 and Continental Illinois in 1984 and the savings and loan crisis in the 1980s.

The reaction to these disturbances was to bail out banks considered too big to fail, a reaction which likely increased the possibility of moral hazard. Many of these issues were resolved by the Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980 and the Basel I Accords, which emphasized the holding of bank capital as a way to encourage prudent behavior. Another problem that has reemerged in modern times is that of asset booms and busts. Stock market and housing booms are often associated with the business cycle boom phase, and busts often trigger economic downturns.

Orthodox central bank policy is to not defuse booms before they turn to busts for fear of triggering a recession but to react after the bust occurs and to supply ample liquidity to protect the payments and banking systems. This was the policy followed by Alan Greenspan after the stock market crash of 1987. It was also the policy followed later in the incipient financial crises of the 1990s and 2000s. Ideally, the policies should remove the excess liquidity once the threat of crisis has passed. Challenges for the Future The key challenge I see facing central banks in the future will be to balance their three policy goals.

The primary goal of the central bank is to provide price stability (currently viewed as low inflation over a long-run period). This goal requires credibility to work. In other words, people need to believe that the central bank will tighten its policy if inflation threatens. This belief needs to be backed by actions. Such was the case in the mid-1990s when the Fed tightened in response to an inflation scare. Such a strategy can be greatly enhanced by good communication. The second policy goal is stability and growth of the real economy.

Considerable evidence suggests that low inflation is associated with better growth and overall macroeconomic performance. Nevertheless, big shocks still occur, threatening to derail the economy from its growth path. When such situations threaten, research also suggests that the central bank should temporarily depart from its long-run inflation goal and ease monetary policy to offset recessionary forces. Moreover, if market agents believe in the long-run credibility of the central bank’s commitment to low inflation, the cut in policy interest rates will not engender high inflation expectations.

Once the recession is avoided or has played its course, the central bank needs to raise rates and return to its low-inflation goal. The third policy goal is financial stability. Research has shown that it also will be improved in an environment of low inflation, although some economists argue that asset price booms are spawned in such an environment. In the case of an incipient financial crisis such as that just witnessed in August 2007, the current view is that the course of policy should be to provide whatever liquidity is required to allay the fears of the money market.

An open discount window and the acceptance of whatever sound collateral is offered are seen as the correct prescription. Moreover, funds should be offered at a penalty rate. The Fed followed these rules in September 2007, although it is unclear whether the funds were provided at a penalty rate. Once the crisis is over, which generally is in a matter of days or weeks, the central bank must remove the excess liquidity and return to its inflation objective. The Federal Reserve followed this strategy after Y2K.

When no financial crisis occurred, it promptly withdrew the massive infusion of liquidity it had provided. By contrast, after providing funds following the attacks of 9/11 and the technology bust of 2001, it permitted the additional funds to remain in the money market once the threat of crisis was over. If the markets had not been infused with so much liquidity for so long, interest rates would not have been as low in recent years as they have been, and the housing boom might not have as expanded as much as it did.

A second challenge related to the first is for the central bank to keep abreast of financial innovations, which can derail financial stability. Innovations in the financial markets are a challenge to deal with, as they represent attempts to circumvent regulation as well as to reduce transactions costs and enhance leverage. The recent subprime crisis exemplifies the danger, as many problems were caused by derivatives created to package mortgages of dubious quality with sounder ones so the instruments could be unloaded off the balance sheets of commercial and investment banks.

This strategy, designed to dissipate risk, may have backfired because of the opacity of the new instruments. A third challenge facing the Federal Reserve in particular is whether to adopt an explicit inflation targeting objective like the Bank of England, the Bank of Canada, and other central banks. The advantages of doing so are that it simplifies policy and makes it more transparent, which eases communication with the public and enhances credibility. However, it might be difficult to combine an explicit target with the Fed’s dual mandate of price stability and high employment.

A fourth challenge for all central banks is to account for globalization and other supply-side developments, such as political instability and oil price and other shocks, which are outside of their control but which may affect global and domestic prices. The final challenge I wish to mention concerns whether implicit or explicit inflation targeting should be replaced with price-level targeting, whereby inflation would be kept at zero percent. Research has shown that a price level may be the superior target, because it avoids the problem of base drift (where inflation is allowed to cumulate), and it also has less long-run price uncertainty.

The disadvantage is that recessionary shocks might cause a deflation, where the price level declines. This possibility should not be a problem if the nominal anchor is credible, because the public would realize that inflationary and deflationary episodes are transitory and prices will always revert to their mean, that is, toward stability. Such a strategy is not likely to be adopted in the near future because central banks are concerned that deflation might get out of control or be associated with recession on account of nominal rigidities.

In addition, the transition would involve reducing inflation expectations from the present plateau of about 2 percent, which would likely involve deliberately engineering a recession—a policy not likely to ever be popular. http://www. clevelandfed. org/research/commentary/2007/12. cfm D. Monetary policy of the Philippines Monetary policy is the monitoring and control of money supply by a central bank, such as the Federal Reserve Board in the United States of America, and the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas in the Philippines.

This is used by the government to be able to control inflation, and stabilize currency. Monetary Policy is considered to be one of the two ways that the government can influence the economy – the other one being Fiscal Policy (which makes use of government spending, and taxes). Monetary Policy is generally the process by which the central bank or government controls the supply and availability of money, the cost of money, and the rate of interest. Types of Monetary Policy Inflation Targeting Inflation targeting revolves around meeting publicly announced, preset rates of inflation.

The standard used is typically a price index of a basket of consumer goods, such as the Consumer Price Index (CPI) in the United States. It intends to bring actual inflation to their desired numbers by bringing about changes in interest rates, open market operations, and other monetary tools. Price Level Targeting Price level targeting involves keeping overall price levels stable, or meeting a predetermined price level. Similar to inflation targeting, the central bank alters interest rates to be able to keep the index level constant throughout the years.

Flourishing and advanced economies opt not to use this method as it is generally perceived to be risky and uncertain. Monetary Aggregates This approach focuses on controlling monetary quantities. Once monetary aggregates grow too rapidly, central banks might be triggered to increase interest rates, because of the fear of inflation. Fixed Exchange Rate Fixed exchange rate is also often called “Pegged Exchange Rate”. Here, a currency’s value is pegged to the value of a single currency, or to a basket of other currencies or measure of value, such as gold.

The focus of this monetary system is to maintain a nation’s currency within a narrow band. Gold Standard In Gold Standard, the government allows its currency to be converted into fixed amounts of gold, and vice versa. This may be regarded as a special kind of Fixed Rate Exchange policy, or of Price Level Targeting. This monetary policy is considered flawed because of the need for large gold reserves of countries to keep up with the demand and supply for money.